Add Title |
A Few Words from the Editors:
The Competition Issue
|
We like competition. We also like themes. Law is competitive, and so the theme of this issue of The Temple 10-Q is, loosely, “competition.” We have solicited pieces on cutting-edge developments in antitrust law, proposals to deal with competition between franchisors and franchisees, and the Supreme Court’s recent Aereo decision on technological competition with the broadcast television industry, among other things. We hope you find these and other developments in Temple’s growing business law community of interest. If you are interested in participating in this community, click here
- The Editors
|
|
|
| | | |
Add Title |
|
Faculty Focus
|
Coming to a Mall Near You: Robo-Seller
|
|
 |
|
Coming to a Mall Near You: Robo-Seller |
|
Increasingly, online merchants, together with brick-and-mortar sellers and data intermediaries,
are knitting together mass data collection, the interconnective power of the “Internet of Things”
and automated algorithmic pricing and selling with their existing retailing and supply-chain
businesses. The result of this coordination is that traditional sales functions such as
competitive intelligence gathering and pricing are being delegated to software “robo-sellers.” In
a recent paper I study the implications of this shift
away from humans to robo-sellers for antitrust law.
Blackletter antitrust law conditions illegality on an anticompetitive “agreement.” To find an
“agreement,” courts, government enforcers, and practitioners tend to focus on finding “intent,”
efforts to sow fear and distrust, and a “meeting of the minds.” These totemic inquiries derive
from a more than a century-old embedded assumption that antitrust regulates sales by human
actors.
I point out that, as sales are increasingly generated and implemented by machines, such standard antitrust inquiries will become less effective. Robo-sellers will function differently and will likely not create the same kinds of evidence that these inquiries rely on. For example, robo-sellers will not need to create an internal paper- or email-trail of communication between sales and marketing employees evidencing an anticompetitive intent. Furthermore, robo-sellers will not be deterred by the possibility of individual criminal punishment – a tool that the DOJ uses to inhibit price-fixing. The outcome may be anticompetitive, but the human element showing intent will have vanished.
Second, robo-sellers will exacerbate an existing gap in the Sherman Act. Oligopolists that achieve price coordination interdependently, without explicit communication, generally escape antitrust enforcement, even when their actions yield supracompetitive (“above market”) pricing that harms consumers. This antitrust dilemma in dealing with parallel behavior by oligopolists will widen: robo-sellers possess certain traits that will probably make them better than humans at achieving supracompetitive pricing without the need for express communication and collusion. For example, the ability to gather and process massive amounts of data will reduce the probability that coordinated pricing would break down due to error or mistake in assessing market conditions.
What can be done about the anticompetitive effects of roboselling? I assess several possible solutions, but find that they will be quite difficult to reconcile with current antitrust law. I conclude that, at least as a feasible second-best result, the FTC should incorporate an evolving approach to robo-sellers. Indeed, the FTC’s ongoing regulatory program has already begun to target the competitive and consumer protection aspects of consumer data collection by sellers. For example, the FTC has already begun to consider the effects of mass data collection and algorithmic processing on consumers from the perspective of disclosure and discrimination (both price and social); efficiencies should exist in broadening the inquiry to include effects on price coordination and cartel behavior.
|
|
| |
| | | |
|
Faculty Focus | |
Add Title |
Delaware Supreme Court Chief Justice Leo Strine: Kohn Lecture | |
 |
|
 | |
David A. Hoffman,
Murray H. Shusterman Professor
in Transactional and Business Law
|
|
Harold Kohn, the Philadelphia lawyer who was the architect of the modern-day class action, will
be honored in memoriam this fall at Temple Law. On October 9, to mark what would have
been Kohn’s 100th birthday, Temple will host a lecture sponsored by Kohn’s eponymous chaired
professorship, and delivered by Delaware Chief Justice Leo E. Strine, Jr.
Harold Kohn “brought many cases to protect ordinary people and their rights against
government and big corporations,” remembers former Temple Dean Robert J. Reinstein. “He
was a remarkable man. Indeed, he is generally recognized as one of the most brilliant
Philadelphia lawyers going back to Andrew Hamilton. I think his greatest accomplishment was
being a principal creator of the modern class action. He turned [Federal Rule of Civil Procedure
23](b)(3) into . . . a powerful instrument in antitrust, securities and consumer cases. Harold
was one of the first to understand that class certification was not merely a procedural device to
consolidate individual claims but that it changed the entire nature of the litigation.“
Kohn became nationally famous for his innovative civil antitrust practice in the 1960s, famously
(and successfully) suing firms ranging from electronics manufacturers to the timber industry.
Though known as the “grandfather of class actions,” Kohn also took on cases involving the First
Amendment, privacy, zoning and commercial transactions. Known as a titan of the Philadelphia
Bar, Kohn was a member of Temple’s Board of Trustees and a generous donor to the Law
School.
Len Barrack, Esq., LAW’68, one of Harold Kohn’s many protégés and a long-time colleague,
credits Kohn with teaching him how to be a great lawyer. He cites Kohn as one of the great
lawyers of the 20th century. The Kohn Chair was jointly endowed by the Barrack Foundation and
the Kohn Foundation, co-directed by Kohn’s widow, Edith Kohn, and his son, Joseph C. Kohn.
Chief Justice Strine’s lecture, Regular (Judicial) Order As Equity: The Enduring Value Of The
Distinct Judicial Role, will be published in the Temple Law Review. Professor Dave Hoffman and
Greg Varallo, LAW ’83, an Executive Director of Richards, Layton & Finger, will comment.
Professor Jonathan Lipson, named as the Harold E. Kohn professor in 2012, invited Chief Justice
Strine to Temple "because the Chief Justice is one of the nation's preeminent jurists, and, like
Mr. Kohn, is concerned about issues of structural integrity and fairness."
Kohn was devoted to many charitable causes. Apart from Temple’s Board of Trustees, he was
chairman of the Board of Governors of Temple University Hospital, and was associated with the
American Civil Liberties Union, the Arronson and Lavine Foundations, the Federation of Jewish
Agencies, the Philadelphia Geriatric Center, the Villanova Law School and Moss Rehabilitation
Center.
More information about the lecture is available here. It is made possible through a generous gift from the Kohn Foundation.
|
| | | |
Faculty Focus | |
Salil Mehra |
The Supreme Court Protects Broadcasters from Competition, for now: ABC v. Aereo |  |
|
|
In ABC v. Aereo, the Supreme Court, in a 6-3 decision, held that Aereo, Inc.’s subscription service - which gave subscribers access over the Internet to a miniature TV antenna and a miniature DVR housed in Aereo’s facility, allowing them to record over-the-air broadcast television signals (like the ones transmitted by your local ABC affiliate) and to re-transmit those recordings to themselves at a later time over the Internet - infringed the broadcasters’ copyrights in their programming.
The Copyright Act gives the owners of the copyright in an “audiovisual work” – an episode, say, of “The Good Wife,” or “CSI: Miami” - the exclusive right to (among other things) “perform the copyrighted work publicly,” which is defined to include “transmit[ting] or otherwise communicat[ing] a performance . . . of the work . . . to the public.” So the narrow question in the case was: did Aereo “transmit or otherwise communicate a performance” of last night’s episode of The Good Wife “to the public”?
On behalf of a group of 36 copyright law professors, I co-authored an amicus brief arguing that it did not, largely on the ground that Aereo was simply providing equipment enabling individual consumers to do something copyright law allows them to do: to record for themselves, and play back to themselves, over-the-air TV broadcasts. [The brief is available
online at http://tinyurl.com/p53gnke]. It’s just like giving (or leasing) to each of them a rooftop TV antenna connected to a DVR; nobody would suggest that the supplier of that equipment was “publicly performing” copyrighted works. Enabling a million such private performances of The Good Wife, we argued, does not equal a public performance; a million times zero is still zero.
We were delighted when we saw that Justice Scalia’s opinion cited, and relied quite heavily upon, our arguments – though our delight was tempered by the fact that Justice Scalia wrote in dissent (on behalf of himself and Justices Thomas and Alito).
Justice Breyer’s opinion for the majority took a different tack, rejecting our rooftop-antenna-plus-DVR metaphor for a different one: that Aereo is, in effect, a cable system. Cable systems re-transmit over-the-air television broadcasts to paying customers all the time; in fact, they are required to do so (by the so-called “must-carry” provisions of a different statute, the Communications Act). And § 111 of the Copyright Act – one of the most impenetrable and complex provisions of federal law I have ever encountered – makes them liable as infringers when they do (and, simultaneously, provides them with a statutory license for doing so, at a statutorily set rate payable to the broadcasters).
Aereo, the Court held, is doing what cable systems do: re-transmitting over-the-air broadcast TV signals to its subscribers. Cable systems pay a royalty for the privilege, and it would upset Congress’ “regulatory purpose” in this “intricate regulatory scheme” to allow Aereo to offer the same service to consumers on a royalty-free basis.
The Court was presented with arguments on the broadcasters’ side that could have had major implications for copyright law and for the many industries – from online streaming to cloud computing to social media – who are dependent upon settled understandings of their copyright liability. The majority, I’m happy to say, declined the opportunity to adopt them. Justice Breyer takes great pains, at several points in the opinion, to emphasize the narrow scope of its holding. While Congress did intend the re-transmission provisions “to apply broadly to cable companies and their equivalents”, it didn’t “intend to discourage or to control the emergence or use of different kinds of technologies,” and the Court’s “limited holding today” won’t have that effect. Id.
“Questions involving cloud computing,[remote storage] DVRs, and other novel issues not before the Court, as to which ‘Congress has not plainly marked [the] course,’ should await a case in which they are squarely presented.”
This case, the Court repeats at several junctures, is just about broadcast television and the re-transmission of over-the-air broadcast TV signals. Congress has made a choice about what you may or may not do with those signals: anyone who re-transmits them (like the cable companies do) must pay royalties to the broadcasters when they do so. It is only Aereo’s “overwhelming likeness to the cable companies targeted by the 1976 amendments [to the Copyright Act],” and the “many similarities between Aereo and cable companies” viewed “in terms of Congress’ regulatory objectives,” id.,that carried the day here.
So if you’re not doing that – re-transmitting over-the-air broadcast TV signals – you can continue to go about your business without worrying unduly about the implications of this decision. Because the decision has little or nothing to say about any content-delivery or content-storage platforms that deal with the vast array of non-broadcast-TV content, it is likely to have limited consequences for larger questions of copyright law outside of broadcast TV (though it will, of course, have major implications for broadcast television economics). And I don’t think I’m giving away any secrets here when I say that over-the-air television broadcasting is probably not where the action is going to be over the next 10 or 20 years, as content continues its migration from broadcast TV to other platforms (cable, cellular network, wireless Internet). Precisely the way Justice
Breyer intended it, I believe.
|
| | |
Alumni Focus | |
Goodwill Indemnity |
Goodwill Indemnity: Another Approach to “Competition” between Franchisors and
Franchisees |  |
|
| |
|
Gokhan E. Tolay, SJD ‘14
Franchising is a growing business model in the U.S. As franchising grows,
however, franchisors can compete with their franchisees over the right to goodwill generated by the franchisee. I have recently completed a dissertation in Temple’s doctoral program that examines legal mechanisms to address expropriation of goodwill generated by franchisees, and proposes an alternative solution.
The franchising model permits the franchisor to impose strict terms and
conditions to protect and enhance its brand name. As a result, franchise contracts are
often standard form contracts drafted by the franchisor and presented on a "take it or
leave it" basis. Although these typically one-sided contracts may be necessary to prevent
franchisees from harming the franchisor’s brand name, in practice, the franchisors’
contractual power can lead to franchisor-opportunism, in particular through wrongful
terminations, onerous transfer restrictions, and so on.
Currently, U.S. law struggles to provide appropriate solutions to deal with this
problem. In most states, courts have developed common law policies that limit particular
franchising practices to prevent the franchisor’s appropriation of the franchisee’s
investment. Nevertheless, courts are reluctant to override express contract provisions with
common law principles. Hence, federal and state legislatures have enacted franchise laws
in order to balance potential power imbalances and to protect franchisees from
opportunism.
While comprehensive “disclosure requirements” have been the highlights of the
regulatory efforts, a number of states have passed “franchise relationship laws” that
considerably restrain franchisors’ contractual power. These statutes typically require
franchisors to show “good cause” for terminations and non-renewals, in some cases
before making any adverse decision. Nevertheless, state relationship laws have been
criticized for being harmful to the franchising sector as they restrict franchisors’
termination power, and thus, encourage franchisee-opportunism. Accordingly, the
majority of the states have not enacted franchise relationship laws.
As current laws fail to provide a fair solution for both parties, my dissertation
offers an alternative theory drawn from the European concept of “goodwill recoupment.”
Under the proposed approach, once a franchise comes to an end, the franchisee would be
entitled to a payment for goodwill lost to the franchisor. This solution differs from
existing theories in the U.S. legal system mainly because the recovery does not depend on
the franchisor’s intentional wrongdoing. If and to the extent that a franchisee has positive
local goodwill, the transfer of this value to the franchisor upon cessation justifies the
payment. Unlike existing U.S. laws, however, the payment aims to recoup only a limited
expected period of time in which the franchisor’s extra earnings might still be traced back
to the franchisee’s efforts. Therefore, the recoupment doctrine offers a narrow but relatively precise protection for franchisees’ goodwill. Moreover, because the proposed
solution targets the economic effect of franchisor-opportunism, there is no need for strict
termination restrictions.
While I do not expect courts or legislatures to enact this proposal immediately,
my hope is that it provides a basis for a richer discussion of the balance of power between
franchisors and franchisees. The proposed approach is a more tailored solution to
franchisor opportunism than those currently used in the U.S. legal system. It would allow
the franchisee to receive a fair return for its intangible investment without constraining
the franchisor’s monitoring power and flexibility. Ultimately, this approach would reduce
both franchisee and franchisor opportunism, and incentivize investment and cooperation.
| | | |
Alumni Update | |
Goodwill Indeminity In |
Competing Outside the Courtroom:
“Trying” the Deal
|
|
 | |
|
Sandra Hill, LAW ’14, Associate, Cozen O’Connor
Temple Law School has long been known for its trial advocacy programs. What some may not
know is that its transactional programs are growing fast, and provide students with innovative
hands-on opportunities to develop competitive business transactional skills, such as negotiating
and drafting corporate documents
During my 3L year, I had the opportunity to immerse myself in transactional law at Temple. In
the fall, I registered for a new course—Negotiating and Drafting Corporate Transactions—
taught by Professors Ed Ellers and Jonathan Lipson. In the spring, I was chosen to participate on
Temple’s LawMeets Transactional Team, coached by Professors Ellers and Lipson.
In the Negotiating and Drafting course, I worked closely with my co-counsel, Pat Bianchi (LAW
’14), other classmates, and the professors on a simulated asset purchase transaction. The
course included assignments such as an engagement letter, a nondisclosure agreement, a letter
of intent, and the final asset purchase agreement. Throughout the semester, we learned the ins
and outs of each part of the deal. We learned not only how to draft these agreements, but also
how to prepare and negotiate the documents.
Professors Ellers and Lipson taught us that coming to a deal isn’t just about winning or losing—
it’s about understanding, and developing persuasive rationales for, your client’s needs.
Effective negotiating facilitates an organic give and take amongst counsel, which then helps
parties secure deals in their best interests. Although we learned that transactional practice
involves competition among the parties, it also requires cooperation in order to make the deal
work.
Based on our work in this course, Pat Bianchi, Chip More (LAW ’14), Rich Barzaga (LAW ’15),
and I were selected to represent Temple in a nationwide transactional skills competition. This is
much like a “moot court,” but for developing deal lawyers. This year, it involved drafting and
negotiating an indemnification agreement. Each team prepared for negotiations by drafting the
agreement and marking up revisions made by opposing teams.
After drafts and comments were exchanged, Pat and I had the opportunity to spend the day in
New York, and Chip and Rich in Chicago, negotiating with (and against) teams from other law
schools to reach a deal on behalf of our clients. We received constructive feedback while being
judged by firm attorneys and in-house counsel. This feedback was invaluable and gave us an
unbiased opinion on both our strengths and weaknesses.
These experiences helped me develop skills and insights that will better enable me to compete
in the marketplace for legal services. While transactional lawyers do not compete in the same
ways that trial lawyers do, I learned that both types of practice share important foundational
skills, including the ability to identify appropriate goals for a client and to develop and
implement strategies and tactics that advance the client’s interests, in particular through reasoned, persuasive argumentation. While I don’t plan to try many cases, my experience in
Temple’s business law program prepared me well to “try the deal.”
|
|
| | |
|
|
|
|
|
| | Temple Business Law in Action | | |
|
|
Temple business law often has an impact in the real world. If you have an important piece of business law news – e.g., you closed a novel transaction, litigated a major case – click here or use the brag box (above) to let us know.
|
|
|
|
| |
Edward Ellers was quoted by NBC10 in coverage of gaming licenses and casino closings in Atlantic City on July 16, 2014 and July 20, 2014. NBC10 News
|
|
| |
David Hoffman published Whither Bespoke Procedure,(2014 Ill. L. Rev. 389). This article casts a wide net
for examples of private contracts governing civil procedure, and finds a decided absence of evidence.
This is a surprising finding given recent claims about the prevalence of procedure-trumping clauses in a
variety of contexts.(link) He also presented Intuitions About Contract Formation at the International workshop on Behavioral Legal Studies at Hebrew University and at Bar-Ilan University
Faculty of Law. He was recently identified as one of the top ten most cited law professors in the country in the field of Law and Social Science (link), and was appointed the Murray H. Shusterman Chair in Transactional and Business Law.
|
|
| |
Ken Jacobsen presented Legal Issues Surrounding the Ownership and Operation of a Professional Sports Team at the CLE program on April 26th for Alumni Weekend. He was a guest speaker on career opportunities in the legal profession at the Temple University Pre-Law Society on April 9th.
|
|
| |
Tom C.W. Lin, CEOs and Presidents, 47 UC Davis Law Review 1351 (2014). This article deciphers a long-standing paradigm of power — the President as CEO — and offers an original and better legal understanding of executive governance. (link) Professor Lin also served as an invited discussant in Enhancing Prudential Standards in Financial Regulations, a conference at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia and served on a panel on Financial Complexity
at the AALS Mid-Year Meeting on Blurring the Boundaries in Finance and Corporate Law in Washington DC. He was quoted in CorporateCounsel.net on June 16, 2014 on how presidents and CEOs differ, and he was quoted in Mondovisione on June 10, 2014 on the SEC’s attention to cybersecurity.
|
|
| |
Salil Mehra published Secondary Liability, ISP Immunity, and Incumbent Entrenchment, 62 Am. J. Comp. L. 685 (2014) (with M. Trimble) (invited submission). This Article questions whether statutes concerning secondary liability of Internet service providers contributes to incumbent entrenchment. The current laws and industry self-regulation may hamper the entry of new service providers into the market and thereby retard the technological progress that best serves society.
(link)
|
|
| |
Eleanor Myers was appointed by the Board of Directors of the NCAA as Vice Chair of the Division 1 Committee on Infractions (COI). This is the membership body that adjudicates charges of major violations of NCAA rules brought by NCAA staff against member institutions, coaches, and other involved individuals. Eleanor has been a member of the COI since 2009. She and Professor Rob Bartow
with whom she co-teaches the award winning Integrated Transactional Program (ITP), have introduced a live client experience into the course this year. ITP, which is offered primarily to second year students (or third year evening students), centers around simulated clients involved in business and family related transactions. Students interview and counsel clients, negotiate and draft documents, make board presentations, appear before regulators and manage their work within a simulated law firm. This year, students will also be creating wills and associated end-of-life planning documents for First Responders as part of national The Wills for Heroes program. Wills for Heroes at Temple Law School is managed by
Kathy Mandelbaum, in association with Jennifer Bretschneider.
|
|
| |
David Post presented Art Law for Artists at the Philadelphia Academy of Fine Arts. He also presented Post on Copyright at the Pennsylvania Bar Intellectual Property Institute.
|
|
| |
Brishen Rogers Justice at Work: Minimum Wage Laws and Social Equality, 92 Tex. L. Rev. 1543 (2014). This article defends minimum wage laws on grounds of justice, building on well-known arguments that a just state will not only redistribute resources but will also enable citizens to relate to one another as equals.(link) Professor Rogers also
co-authored a Brief Submitted by Professors of Labor and Employment Law Amicus Curiae, Browning-Ferris Industries of California, Inc., d/b/a Newby Island Recyclery & FRP-II, LLC, d/b/a/ Leadpoint Business Services, NLRB (Jun. 26, 2014) (Case 32-RC-109684)(link). He co-organized and co-facilitated the seminar The Role of Law in Structures of Global Production at Harvard Law School, June 4-6 2014.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Vice Chancellor J. Travis Laster (Del.) spoke to students and faculty in April, 2014, on recent developments in Delaware Law.
|
|
|
|
|
|
| | Upcoming Events | | |
|
|
|
October 9, 2014 | |
|
Inaugural Harold E. Kohn Lecture, featuring the Honorable Leo E. Strine, Chief Justice, Delaware Supreme Court | |
|
|
October 24, 2014 | |
| Temple Law Review Symposium: The (Un)Quiet Realist: Building and Reflecting on the Contributions of Bill Whitford | |
|
|
| »See Full Events Calendar | |
|
|
| | |
| Contact us | |
| | |
|
|
Click here to send us your comments and suggestions.
|
|
|
|
| Make a Gift to Temple Law | |
|